首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
文章检索
  按 检索   检索词:      
出版年份:   被引次数:   他引次数: 提示:输入*表示无穷大
  收费全文   904篇
  免费   26篇
财政金融   203篇
工业经济   38篇
计划管理   144篇
经济学   201篇
综合类   10篇
运输经济   5篇
旅游经济   9篇
贸易经济   132篇
农业经济   85篇
经济概况   102篇
邮电经济   1篇
  2023年   6篇
  2022年   7篇
  2020年   17篇
  2019年   13篇
  2018年   15篇
  2017年   20篇
  2016年   17篇
  2015年   10篇
  2014年   24篇
  2013年   67篇
  2012年   25篇
  2011年   22篇
  2010年   23篇
  2009年   39篇
  2008年   18篇
  2007年   26篇
  2006年   39篇
  2005年   27篇
  2004年   22篇
  2003年   31篇
  2002年   22篇
  2001年   24篇
  2000年   14篇
  1999年   25篇
  1998年   23篇
  1997年   20篇
  1996年   15篇
  1995年   12篇
  1994年   15篇
  1993年   16篇
  1992年   26篇
  1991年   17篇
  1990年   7篇
  1989年   10篇
  1988年   6篇
  1987年   12篇
  1986年   12篇
  1985年   12篇
  1984年   17篇
  1983年   14篇
  1982年   15篇
  1981年   15篇
  1980年   16篇
  1979年   11篇
  1978年   11篇
  1977年   11篇
  1976年   8篇
  1975年   9篇
  1974年   6篇
  1972年   8篇
排序方式: 共有930条查询结果,搜索用时 46 毫秒
51.
Tracing the income patterns of individual farm operators whose major source of income is generally derived from farming indicates that off-farm income is becoming an increasingly important income component. The relative importance of off-farm income has nearly quadrupled during the last 20 years, rising from about 10 percent of total income to about 37 percent of total income. Most of this off-farm income can be traced to wages and salaries. These fractions are heavily dependent upon relative income levels. In 1970, very low income farmers posted an aggregate net farm loss whereas the $15,000 - $20,000 class secured about three-quarters of their total income from farm sources. In this same year, wages and salaries were generally the prime off-farm income source for farmers with an assessed income of less than $20,000. Dividends and interest were more important to farmers with an income in excess of $20,000. These differences are faithfully reflected in the regional compilations. As a percent of total income, off-farm income ranged from 41 percent in Ontario to about 29 percent in Quebec. The composition of off-farm sources also varies considerably between regions. In 1970 the income position of taxable unincorporated farm operators (who relied on the farm for their major source of income) remained relatively unfavorable. These farmers still had one of the lowest average incomes of any major occupational class in Canada, with an income distribution which was relatively equally distributed between income classes and not unlike that of the national average. These assessed income statistics, of course, are not necessarily indicative of the welfare position of the respective occupational classes. The calculations conducted are simply illustrative of how income tax statistics can be utilized to facilitate our understanding of the income structure in primary agriculture today. The exercise simply underlines the observation that: The fact that there are conceptual differences between income tax data and other data sources should not detract from the usefulness of the income tax data …. Income tax statistics can stand as an independent data source for the analysis of a variety of issues [13]. For many purposes the tax definition of a farm operator may be more operational than the concept of a farmer as defined in the Census of Agriculture. We might profit considerably from further analyses which attempt to disaggregate Census farms into more homogeneous farm-types using the tax statistics available.  相似文献   
52.
53.
54.
55.
56.
Are the agricultural policy reforms embodied in the Uruguay Round consistent with meeting domestic policy objectives such as providing adequate food security, environmental protection and viability of rural areas? This article examines the claim that agriculture deserves more price support and import protection than other sectors because of the non‐marketed externalities and public goods it produces jointly with marketable food and fibre (agriculture’s so‐called ‘multifunctionality’). Do these unrewarded positive externalities exceed the negative externalities from farming by more than the net positive externalities produced by other sectors? To what extent are those farmer‐produced spillovers under‐supplied, and what are the most efficient ways to boost their production to the socially optimal levels? The article concludes that there is little trade‐off required to meet domestic policy objectives on the one hand and agricultural protection reform objectives as embodied in WTO rules on the other.  相似文献   
57.
58.
59.
60.
设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号